Though
perceptive people have been analysing country risk since times immemorial
(observations of many famous travellers since Antiquity who have left us their
memoirs often include useful information in that sphere), the formalization of
the exercise is only a few decades old. The re-emergence of sovereign lending
in a big way from the late 1960’s, meant increasing bond issues, and then large
syndicated bank loans following the oil shocks of the 1970’s. Directly
concerned financial institutions, helped with the growing importance of rating
agencies, decided that it was time to look “scientifically” at countries’
ability to pay.
There
was probably one of the original sins of the game, with the whole effort
concentrating on the ability to service and reimburse external debt. It left
aside all the other cross-border activities such as trade and investment which
had their own risk patterns, not always linked to currency cash flows. For most
analysts, it all became a mere accounting exercise. It left aside the human,
political and social aspects, often ignoring geopolitics altogether. It sought
a one-size-fits-all methodology, and comparative tables as to which country was
“better” or “worse” than another. It introduced totally false premises such as
the famous statement by Citibank’s Walter Wriston to the effect that “Countries
do not go broke, and they do not disappear”. The serious gap in teaching
economic and financial history, or mere geography, in the educational
establishments of some countries is reflected here. Countries have appeared and
disappeared throughout history, a process still going on, and both old and new
countries can go broke, both de facto and de jure (obviously the chairman of
Citibank had never read about the “faillite des deux-tiers” formally declared
by a Republican French government of old.
This
paper only aims to be a sampler of some current mistakes in looking at country
risk. It is not a full methodology handbook, though I am ready and available to
expand on the subject conceptually, as I have done on many occasions during my
nearly 38-year analytical career, 32 of which devoted to Latin America but also
encompassing Europe, the Middle East and the Caucasus. I have advised the
InterAmerican Development Bank on its analytical methodology in the 1990’s,
lectured on the subject on four continents, and trained many corporate and
financial sector analysts as well as academics in modern techniques. My contact
details are in the heading of this paper. This note can be circulated or published
freely, as long as I am given full credit.
A Personalised
Approach
The first sin of most country risk analysts is to look at a country
intrinsically in terms of risk, whereas they should start by asking: “what am I
or my client planning to do there”. This is the weakness of the rating agencies
(whose reliability was much affected by the Asian and Argentine crises, both of
which they failed to predict). They have to come up with a single “judgment”.
Let
me illustrate this with the striking example of the Lebanon at the height of
its civil conflict on the 1970’s and 80’s. Prima facie, it would have been the
epitome of worst possible country risk. But look again at the particular case
of three business risks from abroad into the Lebanon.
The
owners of the Beirut Holiday Inn hotel, on the dividing line of the conflict,
obviously had the short end of the stick (and were in legal disputes with their
insurers for years as to how the conflict could be legally defined for the
purpose of cover). Definitely a bad risk. However, if you had a sovereign loan
to Lebanon, which at the time had a very low public debt, more than covered by
external reserves mainly in gold safely kept outside the country, your risk was
neutral. In fact, despite the sharp subsequent deterioration of the country’s
public finances, and the continuing political instability, the country has yet
to fail on its debt service. A third example would be an exporter of flat glass
to the Lebanon, with a warehouse in Cyprus, which became the main entrepot base
during the conflict. After each of the many ceasefires, households and
businesses would repair their broken windows and glass panes. That foreign
supplier never had it so good as during the civil war, and was probably paid
without problem too. Positive risk.
In
short, one country, at the same moment of time, three businesses, three
different risk conclusions. Not something you could deduce from Standard and
Poor’s.
This
has a corollary when it comes to remedial action taken under salvation or remedial
programmes from foreign lenders, bilateral or multilateral organisations. The
important thing is to make sure that the right problem is diagnosed and
treated. The country crisis viruses have been mutant, starting with balance of
payments and currency cash-flow crises, but soon turning (not least often as a
consequence of the palliative measures taken against the first problem), into
fiscal crises, with several massive defaults of the banking system thrown-in
for good measure.
The
best example of such behaviour was the handling of the Mexican crisis of
1991/92, which paradoxically was an old fashioned currency cash flow shortage.
In order to treat it, in a country which had a balanced budget and single digit
inflation, the foreign ju-ju doctors obliged the country to raise domestic
interest rates to three digits. The result was recession, inflation, a bankrupt
banking sector and a gaping budget deficit. All of these could have been
avoided with a U$ 50 bn currency facility, which came partially and much later,
after all the damage was done.
The Obsession
with GDP
An indecent number of results, investigations and theories, are based on
comparisons measured as a % of GDP. These are not approximations and orders of
magnitudes, but detailed edifices with two decimals. This is ridiculous. We all
know that GDP is a nebulous and capricious figure, the first estimate for which
is not available until well into the following year, after which it is often
corrected (up or down) in subsequent years, to which one has to add base-date
and composition changes, and the impact of erratic exchange rates. Even the
components of GDP are uncertain, not least when most of the countries one
analyses have a substantial black economy, the quantification of which is
problematic.
What
matters, particularly when one is talking of debt and payments are the actual
quantities. Irrespective of how large the debt or its servicing are as a
percentage of a phantom GDP, the important thing is how much money it is, and whether the fiscal,
currency and borrowing resources for such an amount are available from
different potential sources. Brazil’s current interest bill on its public debt
of nearly U$ 1000 bn is U$ 10 million per
hour (24/7).
Current vs. Trade
Account
As mentioned earlier, balance of payments analysis has traditionally
been the kernel of country risk evaluation. Here again, it started on the wrong
foot and kept at it. Admittedly, high commodity prices and other changes in
terms of trade and investment have meant that few countries today (particularly
in Latin America, but also elsewhere) have severe external problems. In fact,
many have record levels of reserves. However, the situation may go into reverse
one day (Mexico in 2007 had a non-oil trade balance deficit of some U$ 55 bn,
with a falling oil output which, barring reforms, may mean an end to its oil
exporting capacity in the medium term).
Probably
one of the most used and also most irrelevant ratios used in traditional
country risk analysis has been Debt Service as a % of Exports. This stupidly
presupposes that export revenue could and should primarily be destined to debt
service. It also presupposes that export revenue (or the resulting currency)
accrues to the government treasury (which is true in some countries but they
are the small minority). It forgets the fact that the country also needs to
import. If it only imports Champagne and Cognac, these could be done away with,
but is a country supposed to stop importing the energy with which to operate,
food with which to feed its population, and the intermediate and capital goods
with which its various sectors develop, in order to service debt? There is only
one such experiment in modern times, hat of Rumania’s last Communist leader,
Ceaucescu, who in his final years left the population cold and starving in
order to repay all the country’s foreign debt, including penalty interest. You
know what happened to him as a result. “Penalty” interest took a completely new
dimension.
A
more logical ratio, which nobody ever uses, would possibly be Debt Service as a
% of the Trade Surplus, which is the money left after imports have been paid
for. Even then it is insufficient, because the real measure of external health
is not the Trade but the Current Account (which includes interest payments). A
good measure of the ability to service external debt should be Interest as a %
of the Gross Current Account (which I would define as all current transactions
but excluding interest payments). I would then use the overall balance of payments
in a similar way to deal with capital repayments.
Having
said all this, the whole exercise has become somewhat sterile because in the
meantime, though many analysts, journalists and politicians talk about the
problems of “external debt”, the virus has mutated into a wider definition,
that of Public Debt, most of which is internal and therefore irrelevant to the
currency flow problems.
The Fiscal
Situation
There is not a lot of in-depth dedicated literature on country risk
methodology, but at the height of the 1980’s debt crisis, two prestigious
publications on the subject were published. One was written by a senior
director at the largest Swiss bank of the time, and another (published by
EUROMONEY magazine) was from the pen of a bank economist who had also worked at
all the main multilateral agencies. Both committed all the sins described
above, but the major flaw they had in common was that they hardly mentioned, if
at all, the main problem befalling the crisis stricken countries: the fiscal
situation.
In
the 1980’s, the crisis was mainly (if not entirely) due to the substantial rise
in the interest bill of indebted countries, which had accumulated debt
throughout the 70’s and in the early 80’s), after the post-Iranian revolution
second oil shock caused a rise in inflation, and therefore interest rates.
Contrary to the bond issues of the previous century and a half, these loans
were at floating rates.
The
rise in interest rates on public foreign debt obviously created an extra demand
on currency resources, but what nearly everybody overlooked, is that it also
paid havocs with budgets. Worse was to come. In an effort to stop another
problem (the flight of capital), countries were coerced to increase domestic
interest rates, often to stratospheric levels as they had right rates of
inflation. The combined impact of costlier foreign and domestic debt service
led to a rapid deterioration of fiscal balances, none of which was very healthy
to start with. None of the movers and shakers appeared to notice. In fact,
there were many proposals to “solve” the debt crisis by replacing foreign
borrowing (say at 8 %) by domestic borrowing (costing say 20 %), with the prior
effort of developing a domestic capital
market.
As
the situation became untenable and debt restructuring followed debt
restructuring, sometimes before the previous programme could even by
implemented, countries fell in and out of contravention to their IMF
agreements. In the late 1980’s, in an effort to save the increasingly shaky
reputation of the crisis managers, someone came up with the idea to change the
definition of fiscal deficit. They invented the Primary Balance, and made it
the target.
Basically,
the authors of this aberration decided that by taking away from the figures the
worst reflection of the problem, they would make it more presentable. To the
extent, as described earlier, that the interest bill had become the main
expenditure element in the budget, ignoring it was akin to a clinical director
to instruct all doctors and radiologists to omit from their written diagnosis
any threatening illness which may turn up in the examinations.
This
of course throws the baby away with the water, forgetting that the purpose of
the analysis is not to show up artificially distorted figures, or apply
cosmetics to a dead body, but to find out how much money the country needs in
order to pay its main obligation. The interest bill is not a vague virtual
notion but a real expense (and, at the risk of labouring the point), the main
expense. In most cases, contrary to capital repayments or other items of
expenditure, it cannot even be delayed or rescheduled.
It
was to be hoped that this concept, invented as was mentioned to save face in
relation to a specific Mexico-IMF agreement, will soon come to pass. On the
contrary, it has not only survived, but has developed into the main statistic
quoted when referring to a country’s fiscal situation. The self-delusion has
been so successful that there is a strong movement to extend it even more.
There is now talk of removing from expenditure figures the amounts of
“investments” (as if they were not an expense either, even if their effect is a
durable one). The innocent may think that such games were reserved for
developing countries. Not at all, several EU members, and some of the oldest
and largest, in an effort to artificially squeeze within the 3 % of GDP fiscal
deficit limit, have been lobbying for years in order to change the deficit
definition by excluding capital expenditure from the expense column.
The
consequence of this silliness is that it is often a substantial effort to find
out the exact fiscal situation of a country. Sure, it is available, if you are
an Egyptologist and know your way in excavating the websites and publications
of the public entities in charge of publishing the figures. It is hardly ever
mentioned in the shorter versions of press communiqués.
FOREIGN
INVESTMENT CREATES JOBS? Not necessarily. In fact, for a decade and a
half, foreign investment in Latin American and other developing countries has
been a very mixed blessing.
It
is true that in its heyday, it was hailed as the answer to a maiden’s prayer.
It brought-in badly needed foreign exchange, created jobs for a young and
growing population, contributed to regional development in underprivileged
areas, increased the tax base, and brought-in a technological leap.
For
a long time, it did many of those things, and in some countries, still does.
Unfortunately, in many others, it has been doing the contrary, and even more
unfortunately, the national and international statistical apparatus has not
evolved to distinguish between the various types of foreign investment.
The
best “positive” foreign investment is the green-field, labour intensive
projects, preferably in high-tech industries. A good example of that would be
the giant INTEL chip plant in Costa Rica. So good in fact that you could trace
its impact on the Central American country’s GDP, though in lean years for
chips, the effect was less positive. Marginally less exciting are the natural
resource projects such as a mining and investments. Beyond the initial
construction stage, they are not labour-intensive, and most of the initial cost
consists of imported specialist machinery. If legislation and negotiation were
well conducted, there would be fiscal benefits from royalties and income taxes.
When
it stops being exciting is when a mature business is transferred from one
foreign owner to the other. It appears as a foreign investment in the
statistics, often inflating the totals and allowing for triumphant statements
from the authorities. In practice, no money or new technology enters the
country, no jobs are created except during the week-end preceding the closing,
when printers and sign painters redesign the premises in the new name. If the
buyer has an existing operation in the target country, it will merge it with
its new acquisition, and reduce the combined staff. So much for job creation.
The
worst consequence for jobs were the series of privatisations carried out by
many Latin American countries since the 1980’s, as part of their debt workout
programmes. Admittedly, the buyers (some more than others), brought in new
management and technology, and badly needed investment. What is sure is that
they started by reducing the payroll. Essential? Probably, but the point I am
trying to make is that contrary to legend, foreign investment does not always
equate with job creation. Many times, it does not even equate with better
management, or is not “privatisation” at all, hence the original sale of the
Chilean telephone monopoly to a Spanish state-owed company (idem for its
Armenian equivalent), or the Peruvian steel complex to a government-owned
Chinese group.
Banking Sector’s
Health
As a cause or consequence of systemic crises, major crises in the
banking sector have often accompanied a wider deterioration in a country’s
situation. Though there has been some improvement in the monitoring of the
banking sector in developing countries, most past crises have come as
“surprises”. Something as easy as keeping an eye on the percentage of past-due
loans in the portfolio, is a good start, though it is insufficient. A close
examination of the real quality and efficiency of the supervisors, beyond the
impressive regulations, handbooks and legislative texts proudly handed out to
visiting delegations, is a better approach. The gap between texts and realities
in the developing world is a wide one.
Inflation and
Monetary Policy Monetarists have dominated economic
policy-making for the best part of three decades, and they have perdured for
longer than the undemocratic governments under which most initially flourished.
It
would be very useful if analysts spent some time in the souks, shops and luxury
malls of the countries their visits, and learn something about the real
situation of interest rates. With most countries in Latin American having
inflation rates within the 3 to 10 % range, and official intervention rates
often double that level or more, what the borrowing businessman or consumer actually
pays to his bank, finance company (or loan shark) has no relation at all with
either inflation or the Lombard rate. Even with countries where single-digit
inflation has been achieved (at a great cost), borrowers pay from 20 to 200 %
on mortgage or consumer credits, depending on the country, their status and the
nature of the borrowing instrument.
Why
does it matter? It affects the public impact of monetary policy to the point of
irrelevance. Reducing or increasing the central bank rate by half a point to
“boost” or “restrict” consumption, is really neither here nor there for
consumers paying up to 120 % on their in-store credit cards. In many countries,
such levels of interest are actually illegal, but authorities turn a blind eye.
Similarly,
using monetary policy as a way of controlling inflation, as per the textbook,
is often wholly or partially sterile. The current bout of inflation is mostly
caused by the increase in world energy and food prices. In many countries,
those who have money will use their cars irrespectively of the cost, because
they can afford it, and much of the rest of the population will similarly
continue because it is essential and they have no alternative forms to
transport themselves or their goods. Similarly, to the extent that the
increases have affected basic staple foods, which constitute the bulk of the
consumption of the lower strata of the population, there is little they can do
short of starving. Putting up interest rates, whatever the book says, is not
going to influence how much bread the poor eat in these countries.
Other
Considerations I started this note by stating that it had no
ambitions to be comprehensive. Its aim is to sensitize analysts as to the
necessity to adopt a new approach. Much can be added about the need to study
political and social aspects, ranging from the sheer possibility to
successfully implement some policies in certain societies, to the background of
the economic managers which is a good indication of their future performance
(finding out the subject matter of their doctorate thesis is one way of doing
it).
I
would be the first to admit that much of this is influenced by my Latin
American experience of over three decades, but I think I have tried to make the
points conceptually, because I am convinced they have a more universal
application.
No comments:
Post a Comment